We spent most of our focus in criminal law (and in all of our areas of law) on how law affects incentives
We have not spent any time on how the legal process determines guilt or innocence
Peter Leeson
1979—
“For 400 years the most sophisticated persons in Europe decided difficult criminal cases by asking the defendant to thrust his arm into a cauldron of boiling water and fish out a ring. If his arm was unharmed, he was exonerated. If not, he was convicted. Alternatively, a priest dunked the defendant in a pool. Sinking proved his innocence; floating proved his guilt. People called these trials ordeals. No one alive today believes ordeals were a good way to decide defendants’ guilt. But maybe they should...Medieval judicial ordeals achieved what they sought: a way of accurately assigning guilt and innocent where traditional means couldn’t.”
Leeson, Peter T, 2012, “Ordeals,” Journal of Law and Economics 55: 691—714
Ordeals were only used when there was uncertainty about a person's innocence or guilt
Obvious cases were settled with evidence and witnesses
Accused is either (truly) Innocent or Guilty (with probability p)
Priest observes choice, but does not know true innocence or guilt
Must find a signal such that payoffs create a separating equilibrium where (Innocent: Undergo, Guilty: refuse)
Ordeals "worked" because of iudecium Dei: God would protect the truly innocent and expose the guilty during the ordeal
Priests didn’t actually leave it in God's hands, but cleverly leveraged people's belief in iudecium Dei
If people believe in iudecium Dei
and Accused ranks payoffs:
Then:
Conditional on observing the Accused’s decision to undertake ordeal, Priest knows person is (very probably) innocent
Priest rigs the Ordeal so the accused "miraculously" passes it
Events were religious, sanctimonious, ritualized, Priest had lots of (trusted) discretion
Ordeals only work for people who believe in iudicium Dei
What about “skeptics”?
Known non-believers (or non-Christians) were not presented with Ordeals as an option
In 1215, Fourth Lateran Council rejects the legitimacy of judicial ordeals, banned priests from administering them
Today we have technology that can accurately separate innocence and guilt in very hard cases (e.g. DNA evidence)
Peter Leeson
1979—
“Though rooted in superstition, judicial ordeals weren’t irrational. Expecting to emerge from ordeals unscathed and exonerated, innocent persons found it cheaper to undergo ordeals than to decline them. Expecting to emerge...boiled, burned, or wet and naked and condemned, guilty persons found it cheaper to decline ordeals than to undergo them. [Priests] knew that only innocent persons would want to undergo ordeals...[and] exonerated probands whenever they could. Medieval judicial ordeals achieved what they sought: they accurately assigned guilt and innocence where traditional means couldn’t.”
Leeson, Peter T, 2012, “Ordeals,” Journal of Law and Economics 55: 691—714
Norman conquest of England (1066) introduced trial by battle (duellum)
Until 1179, it was England’s primary judicial procedure for deciding land ownership disputes
Most dismiss it as being barbaric, irrational, ineffective solution to disputes
Peter Leeson
1979—
“This paper defends trial by battle. It examines trial by battle in England as judges used it to decide property disputes from the Norman Conquest to 1179. I argue that judicial combat was sensible and effective. In a feudal world where high transaction costs confounded the Coase theorem, trial by battle allocated disputed property rights efficiently,” (342).
Leeson, Peter T, 2011, “Trial by Battle,” Journal of Legal Analysis 3(1): 341—375
Demandant (Plaintiff) challenged Tenant (Defendant) via a writ of right, requesting the crown to issue an order compelling Tenant to appear before a court to defend his property
Court required evidence, such as witness testimony, to settle claims
Feudalism: political & economic power is determined by land-ownership
All land in England is owned by the King, who rents out land to tenants
Rent often in-kind or military service, only centuries later that rents paid in money
Under feudalism, property rights (in land) were extremely sticky
Prohibitively high transaction costs for land ownership
For efficiency, property rights should flow to their highest valued users
Coase Theorem: if transaction costs are low, this is exactly what will happen, so long as rights are clearly defined and tradeable
Ideally, we want disputes, where there is no clear evidence of legitimate ownership (for either way), to go to the party that values the land more
Any auction tends to allocate resources to their highest valued user
Market auction: highest bidder always wins
“Legal” auction: party spending most on attorneys increases likelihood of winning
“Violent” auction: party spending most on champion increases likelihood of winning
All types of auction tend to allocate resources efficiently — to higher bidding party
Problem 1: might be differences in endowments (wealth) that affect WTP; can mitigate with credit markets (but poor access to credit in 10th century England!)
Problem 2: bids are a transfer to the party or institution holding the auction, which creates incentives for rent-seeking
Peter Leeson
1979—
“Illegitimate land disputes, which result from bid recipients’ attempts to raise their incomes instead of from genuinely felt ownership disagreements, undermine property rights. They constitute socially costly rent-seeking activity rather than socially productive ownership resolution. Individuals who confront the specter of rampant rent seeking are insecure in their property rights. They live in constant fear that fraudulent legal challengers will deprive them of their property. Therefore they have weak incentives to invest in their land,” (p.342).
Leeson, Peter T, 2011, “Trial by Battle,” Journal of Legal Analysis 3(1): 341—375
Peter Leeson
1979—
“Why didn’t Norman England’s legal system use “regular” auctions—the first-price ascending-bid variety—to auction contested property rights todisputants instead? Because regular auctions would’ve encouraged more rent seeking than violent ones. As in violent auctions, in regular ones, too, there are bid recipients...If proceeds accrue to the legal system, say to the king, or to the judges, officials have an incentive to permit and create fictitious property conflicts.
“Trial by battle’s violent auctions encouraged less rent seeking than regular auctions—and thus were less socially costly—because they generated lower bid receipts, which motivate rent-seeking behavior,” (p.342).
Peter Leeson
1979—
“First, unlike in a regular auction, in trial by battle’s violent auction both the higher bidder and the lower bidder must pay their bids. Expecting the higher-valuing disputant to outbid him, the lower-valuing disputant is therefore encouraged to bid less. That, in turn, allows the higher-valuing disputant to bid less too. In contrast, in a regular auction only the higher bidder pays his bid. The lower-valuing user therefore has no incentive to bid anything lower than his full valuation of the disputed right...As a result, disputants spend more to affect the allocation of disputed property rights in a regular auction than they do in trial by battle’s violent one.
Peter Leeson
1979—
Second, unlike in a regular auction, in trial by battle’s violent auction the higher-biddingdisputant only wins the auction probabilistically. The higher-spending disputant who sends a better champion to the arena is more likely to win the disputed right, but it’s possible for the lower-spending disputant’s inferior champion to upset him. In contrast, in a regular auction the higher-bidding disputant always wins the auction. The “randomness” in trial by battle’s violent auction, which doesn’t exist in a regular auction, reduces the value of making higher bids. That, in turn, encourages disputants to bid less. The result again is that disputants spend more to affect the allocation of disputed property rights in a regular auction than they do in trial by battle’s violent one,” (p.360).
Peter Leeson
1979—
“Once each disputant knows who their adversary has hired, and thus has a good idea about what he spent on the trial, battle is unnecessary. At this point both parties know the trial’s probabilistic outcome. They can save time and expense by settling their dispute instead. Thus my theory predicts that disputants should’ve settled most trials by battle. In fact it predicts that disputants should’ve always settled unless they had sufficiently different assessments of their champions’ comparative skill, or bargaining itself proved too costly and thus broke down...As long as the victorious champion’s identity isn’t a fore-gone conclusion, a mutually beneficial bargaining range that permits settlement exists. Disputants have an incentive to settle until battle is over,” (p.363).
Trials by battle were a mechanism meant to induce settlement between the parties, so long as it was unclear who would win
Courts took pains to minimize the social cost of the trials
Peter Leeson
1979—
“Historian of trial by battle M. J. Russell (1980a, 129) has identified 598 cases in England between 1200 and 1250 that mention trial by battle. Disputants actually wagered battle in only 226 of these cases, or 37.8 percent of the time. Champions only fought in 123 of these cases, or 20.6 percent of the time. These data suggest that disputants settled trials by battle nearly 80 percent of the time. Even taking Russell’s lower-most bound of 66.6 percent, the evidence suggests that medieval English disputants overwhelmingly settled under trial by battle. ‘[I]t is abundantly clear that trial by battle in civil cases did from an early time tend to become little more than a picturesque setting for an ultimate compromise’ (Pollock 1912: 295). ‘[B]attles were often pledged but seldom fought’ (Russell 1959, 245),” (p.364).
Peter Leeson
1979—
“My analysis explains how a seemingly irrational legal institution—trial by battle—is consistent with rational, maximizing behavior. It illuminates why this apparently inefficient institution played a central role in England’s legal system for so long. Most important, it demonstrates how societies can use legal arrangements to substitute for the Coase theorem where high transaction costs preclude trade,” (p.364).
Peter Leeson
1979—
“When the transaction cost of trading land is low, and thus property rights in land are fluid, things are different. In this case society can rely on the Coase theorem to reallocate land to higher-valuing users if judges’ initial allocation of contested property is wrong. Trial by battle’s demand-revelation and allocation mechanism is unnecessary. It imposes a cost without a corresponding benefit. Trial by battle is inefficient. Thus my theory predicts that England’s legal system should’ve abandoned trial by battle for deciding land disputes when the transaction cost of trading land fell significantly. The history of trial by battle’s decline in English land disputes supportsthis prediction. In the second half of the twelfth century Henry II introduced important legal changes in England—the so-called Angevin reforms. These changes mark the birth of English common law and the beginning of feudalism’s end in England...In this period traditional feudal property arrangements declined significantly. With them, so did the transaction cost of trading land,” (p.366—367).
Laws themselves have to come from somewhere
Political economy of how laws are determined
Predicting consequences of law
Predicting what law will be
Recommending what law should be
We have developed theories of property/nuisance law, contract law, tort law, criminal law
Looked at how rules of legal liability create/change incentives
Thought about how these rules can be chosen to try to achieve (more) efficient outcomes
Property law
Contract law
Tort law
Criminal law
Administrative costs
Error costs
So theoretically, an efficient legal process (in the real world) is one that minimizes sum of:
We've already seen tradeoff between these two types of costs:
Whaling law: “fast fish/loose fish” vs. “iron holds the whale”
Pierson v. Post (fox hunt case)
Privatizing ownership of land
Not to memorize facts like which liability rules lead to efficient behavior
But to understand and learn how to think about why
This was never a law class, but a class about how to think about the law
1) Incentives matter
(...need I say more?)
2) Efficiency as a goal is a good starting point
3) Coase Theorem: can we depend on people to bargain to efficient outcomes?
4) Efficiency requires incentives to engage in socially productive activities...but in excess can cause rent-seeking
5) A perfect rule may not exist, even in theory...
6) ...and even if it does, it might not be what we want in practice
7) Understand how our conclusions depend on our assumptions
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |