So far, we have been assuming accidents are entirely between strangers who have no personal or economic relationship
We now turn to products liability, an subfield of tort law where the injurer is a business and the victim is a consumer of their product
Worth studying for three reasons
Used to be a minor type of tort case, now a major growing and specialized body of law
Source of growing dissatisfaction with our tort liability system
Accidents are between parties with a contractual relationship
Three main phases of products liability law development
Corresponding to the main type of liability rule used
Pre-1916: No Liability
1916-1960: Negligence
1960—Present: Strict Liability
Since Industrial Revolution, focus on production and economic growth
Some suggest influence of Classical Economists (or at least, their ideas) on weak tort law against business
Some feared excessive liability for producers would threaten business
No Liability for manufacturer
Main law in operation was contract law
Doctrine of privity of contract: only parties to a contract can sue one another
This effectively insulated manufacturers from liability
MacPherson v. Buick (217 N.Y. 382, 1916)
MacPherson had bought a Buick from a NY auto dealer, the car later lost a wheel and ejected him from the car
Buick says they have no privity with MacPherson, only with the dealership
Benjamin N. Cardozo
1870—1938
Associate Justice of U.S. Supreme Court
“If the nature of a thing is such that it is reasonably certain to place life and limb in peril when negligently made, it is then a thing of danger. Its nature gives warning of the consequence to be expected. If to the element of danger there is added knowledge that the thing will be used by persons other than the purchaser, and used without new tests, then, irrespective of contract, the manufacturer of this thing of danger is under a duty to make it carefully. That is as far as we need to go for the decision of this case...If he is negligent, where danger is to be foreseen, a liability will follow.”
MacPherson v. Buick (217 N.Y. 382, 1916)
Court rejected privity, arguing the manufacturer could have reasonably forseen the possibility of such injuries to car’s ultimate users (consumers), and not just the immediate purchaser (dealer)
Shift from 1916—1960 to a negligence rule
Gradual increase in standard of due care owed by manufacturers
Increase in producer liability for breach of warranty
Escola v. Coca-Cola Bottling Co. (24 Cal.2d 453, 1944)
Waitress in restaurant served a Coca-cola bottle that spontaneously exploded, causing injuries
Plaintiff could not offer any evidence that Coca Cola was negligent in its production
Majority opinion (Chief Justice Phil S. Gibson):
“Upon an examination of the record, the evidence appears sufficient to support a reasonable inference that the bottle here involved was not damaged by any extraneous force after delivery to the restaurant by defendant. It follows, therefore, that the bottle was in some manner defective at the time defendant relinquished control, because sound and properly prepared bottles of carbonated liquids do not ordinarily explode when carefully handled.”
Concurring opinion (Justice Roger Traynor):
“[Public policy demands] responsibility be fixed wherever it will most effectively reduce the hazards to life and health inherent in defective products that reach the market...In leaving it to the jury to decide whether the inference has been dispelled, regardless of the evidence against it, the negligence rule approaches the rule of strict liability. It is needlessly circuitous to make negligence the basis of recovery and impose what is in reality liability without negligence. If public policy demands that a manufacturer of goods be responsible for their quality regardless of negligence there is no reason not to fix that responsibility openly.”
Escola v. Coca-Cola Bottling Co. (24 Cal.2d 453, 1944)
Court held Injurer liable under legal doctrine of res ipsa loquitor (“the thing speaks for itself”)
As due care does not entirely eliminate the risk of accidents under this rule, effectively a rule of strict liability for the Injurer
In contract law, sellers are strictly liable for damages caused by products that fail to operate as presented (regardless of negligence), a breach of warranty
However, privity of contract operates here — only those who are a party to the contract may sue (essentially for breach of contract)
Henningsen v. Bloomfield Motors, Inc. (32 N.J. 358, 1960)
Henningsen bought a Chrysler car from Bloomfield Motors (an auto dealer)
Steering mechanism in Henningsen’s Chrysler car failed, causing an accident
Sale contract between Henningsen’s and the manufacturer expressly limited Chrysler’s liability to the original purchaser (dealer), and only for certain types of damages (defective parts, etc.)
Court rejected this limitation, arguing implied warranty of fitness prevailed regardless of any expressed contractual terms to the contrary
Although the victim was not the original purchaser, she:
“in the reasonable contemplation of the parties to the warranty, might be expected to become a user of the automobile. Accordingly, her lack of privity does not stand in the way of prosecution of the injury suit against the defendant Chrysler.”
(\S)
402A:(1) One who sells any product in a defective condition unreasonably dangerous to the user or consumer or to his property is subject to liability for physical harm thereby caused to the ultimate user or consumer, or to his property, if
(a) the seller is engaged in the business of selling such a product, and
(b) it is expected to and does reach the user or consumer without substantial change in the condition in which it is sold.
(2) The rule stated in Subsection (1) applies although
(a) the seller has exercised all possible care in the preparation and sale of the product, and
(b) the user or consumer has not bought the product from or entered into any contractual relation with the seller.
Somewhat misleading to label the rule as “strict liability”
In addition to harm & causation, Plaintiffs must show product is defective in design or manufacture
Or, if it is inherently dangerous, the manufacturer failed to warn consumers of danger
Consider a typical supply and demand model, first for a safe product
Demand: p=a−bq
Supply: p=c
Equilibrium (q⋆,p⋆) q⋆=c+ba;p⋆=c
Consider a typical supply and demand model, first for a safe product
Demand: p=a−bq
Supply: p=c
Equilibrium (q⋆,p⋆) q⋆=c+ba;p⋆=c
Now suppose the product comes with some risk of an accident
Accidents are determined by both parties’:
We need to consider the liability rule in place
Two main alternatives:
Now adjust Demand and Supply to account for accident risk, determined by liability:
Demand with risk: p=a−bq−(1−s)pD
Demand with risk: p=a−bq−(1−s)pD
If s=1 (SL), no change in demand, consumer behaves as if product was perfectly safe
If s=0 (NL), reduce spending exactly by expected damages per unit
Now adjust Demand and Supply to account for accident risk, determined by liability:
Supply with risk p=c+spD
Now adjust Demand and Supply to account for accident risk, determined by liability:
Supply with risk p=c+spD
If s=0 (NL), no change in supply, producer behaves as if product was perfectly safe
If s=1 (SL), raise asking price exactly by expected damages per unit
Regardless of the rule (s), equilibrium quantity is always q⋆⋆! a−b(q)−(1−s)pD=c+spDa−b(q)=c+pD
q⋆⋆ efficient level where marginal social benefit = full marginal social cost (including expected accident costs)
Application of the Coase Theorem: resource allocated efficiently (MSB=MSC) regardless of the assignment of liability!
The price of the product does depend on rule s:
Area B = cq⋆⋆=pNLq⋆⋆
Area A = pDq
Area B + A = total social costs to produce (under Strict Liability s=1)
Producer will always directly bear area B as cost (MC of production)
Liability rule s will determine who will bear cost of area A
The main question is, who is the better insurer?
If accident happens with first unit
Will the level of precaution be optimal regardless of the liability rule? (like output q⋆⋆)?
If s=0 (no liability)
Will the level of precaution be optimal regardless of the liability rule? (like output q⋆⋆)?
If s=1 (strict liability)
Both lead to safer products, assuming low transaction costs
How likely are these to work in practice?
First case (no liability), consumer pays higher price if she can see product is safer
Second case (strict liability) is virtually impossible
Coase theorem fails with these high transaction costs
We saw a strict liability rule is unlikely to achieve efficient level of victim (consumer) care
Further complicates matters if (as they often do), consumers mispercieve risks
Return to our model, let's first look at equilibrium output
Producers correctly perceive probability of accident as p
Suppose consumers misperceive the probability of an accident as αp
Return to our model, let's first look at equilibrium output
Producers correctly perceive probability of accident as p
Suppose consumers misperceive the probability of an accident as αp
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD
c+spD
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD
c+spD
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD=c+spD
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD
c+spD
a−b(q)−(1−s)αpD=c+spD
--
As an example, conside no liability (s=0)
Equilibrium output where: a−b(q)−αpD=c
If α>1, consumers overestimate risk, demand too little output
As an example, conside no liability (s=0)
Equilibrium output where: a−b(q)−αpD=c
If α>1, consumers overestimate risk, demand too little output
If α<1, consumers underestimate risk, demand too much output
Different under strict liability (s=1), we saw equilibrium output is still efficient q⋆⋆
Consumer misperceptions of risk have no effect on output
In other words, when consumers misperceive risk, the liability rule matters for efficiency
In general, the party who more accurately perceives the risk should bear the liability
Supports general historical trend of more strict liability for products
Rule | Injurer Precaution | Victim Precaution |
---|---|---|
No liability | Zero | Efficient |
Strict liability | Efficient | Zero |
Rule | Injurer Precaution | Victim Precaution |
---|---|---|
No liability | Zero | Efficient |
Strict liability | Efficient | Zero |
Rule | Injurer Precaution | Victim Precaution |
---|---|---|
No liability | Zero | Efficient |
Strict liability | Efficient | Zero |
Strict Liability w/Contributory Negligence | Efficient | Efficient |
Rule | Injurer Precaution | Victim Precaution |
---|---|---|
No liability | Zero | Efficient |
Strict liability | Efficient | Zero |
Strict Liability w/Contributory Negligence | Efficient | Efficient |
We also saw before that introducing a defense of contributory negligence restores incentive for Victim to take due care to avoid liability
However, most cases do not accept this as a defense!
Contract law is not an adequate remedy for most product related accidents between Producer and Consumer
In theory, Coase Theorem suggests the parties could bargain to fully internalize the accident risk (between pSL and pNL)
But high transaction costs prevent this:
High cost of contracting in the presence of these remote risks disproportionate to the benefits of a negotiated level of safety
What about accidents where workers are injured on the job?
Or accidents between workers and strangers/customers in course of employment?
Workers injured on the job are similar to products liability
Accidents between worker and stranger are like accidents between strangers
Vicarious liability: one party is held liable for the harm caused by another
Respondeat superior: “let the master answer”
Respondeat superior gives employers incentives to:
Employers are better able to make these decisions (and bear the risks) than employees
Employees are also likely “judgement proof”: unable to pay the full costs of harms
Can implement vicarious liability via:
Which rule is better? Depends:
Historically, employer liability for when employee is the victim was very limited
Employer could avoid liability by demonstrating contributory negligence on part of injured employee
Historically, “fellow servant rule” shielded employers from liability if the cause of the accident to an employee was the action of another employee
Gives incentive for employees to monitor each other
Perhaps works well for small workplaces where coworkers all frequently interact, but not so well for large businesses
In 20th Century, dissatisfaction with common law of workplace accidents led to legislation in all States: workers compensation
Created a form of strict liability for employer
However, amount of compensation for workers was fixed by a schedule of damages by injury, and administered by government agencies rather than courts (& lawsuits)
“The compensation tradeoff”: employee waives right to sue, but is essentially guaranteed a limited of insurance from injury
Benefit to employers: lowers risk of bankruptcy from high damage awards in tort cases
Potential issue in reducing employees incentives for precaution (no defense of contributory negligence), but:
Asbestos is a fibrous material that is an excellent electrical insulator and highly heat resistant, used for decades as a building material
But, inhalation of asbestos fibers can lead to serious conditions such as lung cancer, mesothelioma, heart disease
Since public health developments in 1970s, asbestos is banned as a building material due to safety hazards
1) Compensating differentials in wages
2) Workers compensation laws
Borel v. Fibreboard Paper Products Corporation (1973)
Borel filed personal injury lawsuit against Fibreboard and 9 other asbestos-insulation manufacturers after being diagnosed with mesothelioma
Argued manufacturers should be liable because it asbestos did not come with warning labels
By then, strict liability for manufacturers in products liability
Borel v. Fibreboard Paper Products Corporation (1973)
Sadly, Borel died before the lawsuit was over
Court found these companies were strictly liable, even though Borel was not an employee of Fibreboard
Now, consumers can sue manufacturers directly, without an economic relationship (like employment) — products liability
Suppose a victim was hurt ($1,000 worth of damages) in an accident caused by multiple injurers
Joint liability: victim can sue all injurers combined (as co-defendants) for $1,000
Several liability: victim can sue each injurer separately, but each is only liable for the amount they contributed to the accident
Joint and several liability: law treats all injurers as jointly liable, and victim can sue any of them for the full damages
Joint and several liability applies when:
Good for the Victim
With joint & several liability for asbestos, the claims are increasing faster than the actual injuries
From Wikipedia):
“Asbestos lawsuits in the U.S. have included the following as defendants: manufacturers of machinery that are alleged to have utilized asbestos-containing parts; owners of premises at which asbestos-containing products were installed; retailers of asbestos-containing products, including hardware, home improvement and automotive parts stores; corporations that allegedly conspired with asbestos manufacturers to deliberately conceal the dangers of asbestos; manufacturers of tools that were used to cut or shape asbestos-containing parts; and manufacturers of respiratory protective equipment that allegedly failed to protect workers from asbestos exposure.”
The problem is, you’re not suing the least-cost avoider of the harm!
An excessive amount of rent-seeking and frivolous claims
Asbestos litigation is the longest, most expensive mass tort in U.S. history, involving more than 8,000 defendants and 700,000 claimants. By the early 1990s, "more than half of the 25 largest asbestos manufacturers in the US, including Amatex, Carey-Canada, Celotex, Eagle-Picher, Forty-Eight Insulations, Manville Corporation, National Gypsum, Standard Insulation, Unarco, and UNR Industries had declared bankruptcy. Analysts have estimated that the total costs of asbestos litigation in the U.S. alone will eventually reach $200 to $275 billion." The amounts and method of allocating compensation have been the source of many court cases, and government attempts at resolution of existing and future cases.
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |