What can be privately owned?
What can (and can't) an owner do with her property?
How are property rights established?
What remedies are available when property rights are violated?
William Blackstone
(1723-1780)
“There is nothing which so generally strikes the imagination, and engages the affections of mankind, as the right of property; or that sole and despotic dominion which one man claims and exercises over the external things of the world, in total exclusion of the right of any other individual in the universe.”
Blackstone, William, Commentaries on the Laws of England (1765-1769) Book II, Chapter 1 - Of Property in General
Efficiency would suggest the maximum liberty principle: owners should be able to do whatever they please with their property
...provided they do not interfere with others' property or rights
John Stuart Mill
1806-1873
Mill, John Stuart, On Liberty
Put economically: property owners should be at liberty to do as they please, so long as their actions do not impose an externality on others
In common law, an externality is called a nuisance
Common law appears to approximate the maximum liberty principle
But does it really?
Nice theoretical idea, but not necessarily a fundamental legal maxim
Law distinguishes between different scales of externalities (nuisances):
Affecting only a few people, a private nuisance or a private bad
Affecting a large number of people, a public nuisance, a public bad
Compensatory damages intended to “make the victim whole” by compensating for actual harm done
Temporary: compensate for past harms that have already occurred
Compensatory damages intended to “make the victim whole” by compensating for actual harm done
Permanent: cover (present value of) anticipated future harm
For a private nuisance affecting small number of people, injunction is more efficient remedy
For a public nuisance affecting large number of people, damages are more efficient remedy
What is done in practice for public nuisances?
Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co. 26 N.Y.2d 219, 309 N.Y.S.2d 312 (N.Y. 1970)
Harm to neighbors ($183,000) much less than the value of the investment in the factory ($45 million), would be inefficient to close the factory
If transaction costs were low, neighbors could bargain with plant to mitigate harm (pay it to reduce dirt, smoke, vibrations, etc)
But high transactions costs here (a public nuisance), so court imposed a liability rule to compensate the injured parties
First recognition that sometimes a liability rule is more efficient in some property cases
“[Ordinarily in property law], where a nuisance has been found and where there has been any substantial damage shown by the party complaining, an injunction will be granted.”
“To grant the injunction unless defendant pays plaintiffs such permanent damages as may be fixed by the court seems to do justice between the contending parties. All of the attributions of economic loss to the properties on which plaintiffs' complaints are based will have been redressed ... [and i]t seems reasonable to think that the risk of being required to pay permanent damages to injured property owners by cement plant owners would itself be a reasonably effective spur to research for improved techniques to minimize nuisance.”
“[The initial trial court is ordered] to grant an injunction which shall be vacated upon payment by defendant of.. .permanent damage[s] to the respective plaintiffs.”
What can be privately owned?
What can (and can't) an owner do with her property?
How are property rights established?
What remedies are available when property rights are violated?
John Locke
1632-1704
"Though the earth, and all inferior creatures, be common to all men, yet every man has a property in his own person: this no body has any right to but himself. The labour of his body, and the work of his hands, we may say, are properly his. Whatsoever then he removes out of the state that nature hath provided, and left it in, he hath mixed his labour with, and joined to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his property...that excludes the common right of other men: for this labour being the unquestionable property of the labourer, no man but he can have a right to what that is once joined to, at least where there is enough, and as good, left in common for others," (Ch. V).
Locke, John, 1689, Second Treatise on Government
Fugitive property: property that moves around or has indefinite boundaries (the harder cases)
Examples: oil & gas deposits, whales, foxes
Hammonds v. Central Kentucky Natural Gas Co. 75 S.W.2d 204 (Ky. Ct. App. 1934)
Central KY leased land lying above natural gas deposits
Geological dome lay partly under Hammonds' land
Central KY drilled down and extracted the gas
Hammonds sued, claiming (some of) the gas was his
1) First possession
nobody owns fugitive property until someone possesses it
first to “capture” a resource owns it
Example: Central KY would own all the gas
2) Tied ownership
ownership of fugitive property tied to (possession of) something else (e.g. surface)
Example: Hammonds would own some of the gas (under his land)
Tied using principles of accession: new thing owned by owner of the proximate or prominent property
“Possession is nine-tenths of the law”
Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2 can drill on an area of unowned land.
Suppose:
Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2 can drill on an area of unowned land.
Nash Equilibrium: (Fast, Fast)
A prisoners' dilemma
Equally viewed as tragedy of the commons
Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2 can drill on an area of unowned land.
Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2 can drill on an area of unowned land.
Nash Equilibrium: (Slow, Slow)
Incentivizes efficient use of resource
No need to race to get it first
But perhaps difficult to establish and verify ownership rights
Rules that link ownership to possession
Rules that allow ownership without possession (like tied ownership)
Rules that link ownership to possession
Rules that allow ownership without possession (like tied ownership)
Intended to settle the Western U.S. after Civil War
Citizens could acquire 160 acres of land for free:
Essentially a first possession rule for land
Friedman: caused people spend inefficiently much to gain ownership of the land
David D. Friedman
(1945—)
“The year is 1862; the piece of land we are considering is… too far from railroads, feed stores, and other people to be cultivated at a profit...The efficient rule would be to start farming the land the first year that doing so becomes profitable, say 1890. But if you set out to homestead the land in 1890, you will get an unpleasant surprise: someone else is already there...If you want to get the land you will have to come early. By farming it at a loss for a few years you can acquire the right to farm it thereafter at a profit.”
David D. Friedman
(1945—)
“How early will you have to come? Assume the value of the land in 1890 is going to be $20,000, representing the present value of the profit that can be made by farming it from then on.Further assume that the loss from farming it earlier than that is $1,000 a year.If you try to homestead it in 1880, you again find the land already taken.Someone who homesteads in 1880 pays $10,000 in losses for $20,000 in real estate – not as good as getting it for free, but still an attractive deal...The land will be claimed about 1870, just early enough so that the losses in the early years balance the later gains. It follows that the effect of the Homestead Act was to wipe out, in costs of premature farming, a large part of the land value of the United States.”
What can be privately owned?
What can (and can't) an owner do with her property?
How are property rights established?
What remedies are available when property rights are violated?
Public Good: a good that is non-rival and non-excludable
Rivalry: one use of a resource removes it from other uses
Excludability: ability or right to prevent others from using it (ownership)
Individual bears a private cost to contribute, but only gets a small fraction of the (dispersed) benefit of a good
If individuals can gain access to the good (nonexcludable) without paying, may lead to...
Free riding: individuals consume the good without paying for it
When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overused, congested, and depleted (tragedy of the commons)
When public goods are owned privately, they tend to be underproduced
Implications for efficiency:
This is consistent with the normative framework we have been developing:
Low transaction costs → facilitate exchange
High transaction costs → allocate rights efficiently
Example: Consider clean air
But still two options:
Example: Consider clean air
Compare the relative costs of each option
We've seen two doctrines for how ownership rights are determined
When should a resource become privately owned?
Efficient to privatize a resource where boundary maintenance costs are less than the waste from overuse of the resource
Remember the lesson & example in Demsetz (1967)!
Adverse possession (“squatter's rights”): if you occupy someone else's property for long enough, you become the legal owner, provided:
Benefit: reduces uncertainty over time; allows (otherwise idle) land to be put to use
Cost: owners must incur monitoring costs to protect property
Estray statutes laws governing lost and found property
Discourages theft (thief can't just say “I found it”), increases information spread about lost property
Assuming owners value the property the highest, ensures it gets back to them
Property rights generally are protected by injunctive relief (property rules), BUT
Ploof v. Putnam 81 Vt. 471, 71 A. 188 (1908)
Property rights are not absolute!
Example: in an emergency, it is lawful to violate another's property rights, but must still compensate them for damages
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |